MCO costs for physician services decrease as MCOs gain market power; that is,
as the MCOs attain economies of scale. Once MCOs become established in a
market, they become an almost irresistible force. In most markets, patient
lives are divided between several managed care organizations. However,
MCOs seldom compete in terms of the contracts they offer physicians. They
may compete on the price they will pay for buying practices, but they hold the
line on the contractual rights of the physicians delivering medical care services.
The cost of a practice is a one-time expenditure, but the costs and terms of
physician contracts are long-term expenses that are key to the survival of
MCOs. In many communities, physician contracts used by competing MCOs
have identical terms. Although this might be parallel action based on similar
needs, there also may be substantial collusion to ensure that no plan
undermines the others by granting physicians substantially greater rights. In
other businesses this would be an antitrust violation. MCOs are legally
considered insurance companies, however, and they have McCarron-Ferguson
immunity from federal antitrust laws. [15 U.S.C. § 1011 (1996).] They cannot
be sued for most antitrust activities.
Unfortunately, physicians do not have the same immunity. Independent
physician groups and local medical societies must be alert to potential antitrust
violations. Independent contractor physicians who band together to resist cram-
down contracts from MCOs can be held to have engaged in a group boycott or
other violations of the Sherman Antitrust Act. Such groups have been
prosecuted by the FTC. This limits collective action by physicians to those that
are employees of an MCO. Physicians who are MCO employees can unionize by
following National Labor Relations Board (NLRB) standards. Once in an NLRB-
certified union, they can strike or take other actions. Independent contractor
physicians cannot unionize to gain the protection of the NLRB. For independent
contractor physicians, the only avenue for collective action is to petition their
state legislatures and Congress for statutory protections. Such collective action
to petition the government for redress is protected under the Noerr-
Pennington doctrine as a form of political speech. [
Eastern R.R. Presidents
Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.S. 127 (1961);
United Mine Workers v.
Pennington, 381 U.S. 657 (1965).]
A major problem for physicians who are trying to band together to bargain
more effectively with MCOs has been the lack of both common law and
regulatory guidance. In 1996, the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade
Commission issued guidelines on medical care mergers and joint operating
agreements. [United States Department of Justice & Federal Trade
Commission, Statements of Antitrust Enforcement Policy in Health Care sec.
B1, Statement 8 (August 1996).] Although some commentators have seen
these as greatly expanding physician’s right to take collective action, a close
reading indicates no change from prevailing antitrust rules.
The only safety zones provided in the guidelines are for physician networks that
involve significant shared financial risk and that do not have more than 20% of
the market for exclusive arrangements, or 30% for nonexclusive
arrangements. Although the guidelines say that it is possible to have
complying networks without substantial shared financial risk, the criteria they
use for evaluating these networks imply that it is unlikely many will pass. The
guidelines make clear that informal associations of physicians that engage in
anticompetitive activities, such as boycotts of MCOs or other bargaining
activities, will be treated harshly:
In contrast to integrated physician network joint ventures, such as these
discussed above, there have been arrangements among physicians that
have taken the form of networks, but which in purpose or effect were
little more than efforts by their participants to prevent or impede
competitive forces from operating in the market. These arrangements
are not likely to produce significant procompetitive efficiencies. Such
arrangements have been, and will continue to be, treated as unlawful
conspiracies or cartels, whose price agreements are per se illegal. [Id.
at B(1).]